The current new-type urbanization measures of Chinese government will pull tens of thousands of billions of investment in the infrastructure. However, the government's financial capital is so limited that it is difficult to meet the demand of a large number of infrastructure investment. Thus a model called PPP (Private-Public Partnership) is put forward to solve the shortage of government funding. The infrastructure project using the PPP generally has a quasi public goods attribute, which leads to its low operating revenue unable to take back the private huge initial investment. That means the proper compensation should be given to the private investor, if the government wants the PPP project to be successful. The compensation for the PPP project is not easy to determine before the event because the excessive or insufficient compensation will cause that the project's social welfare or the private interest is damaged. Only the compensation after the event will reduce the enthusiasm of private investment, which will also cause the compensation to be inefficient. Based on the governmental decision-making dilemma for the compensation, a single period compensation contract is introduced for the private investor. The contract specifies that the government should promise the concession revenue before the event to the private investor and then give a certain post-compensation to the investor by comparing the project's real revenue with the concession revenue.When the contract is accepted, the governmental compensation is likely to imply that the private investor show the excessive optimism and confidence on the PPP project's future expectation. That is,the private investor has the overconfidence behavior under the governmental compensation. For this reason, the private overconfidence is considered in the study on the governmental compensation contract for the PPP project.Firstly,the private investor's overconfidence is described by the "Mean-Variance" in which the private overconfidence coefficient is introduced. Thus the private expected utility function related to the overconfidence preference is proposed. Accordingly, the private overconfidence investment strategy is given out and its effect on the governmental optimal compensation contract is studied by the method of Stackelberg game. Secondly, under the circumstance that the private overconfidence can't be observed, the design and selection of governmental optimal compensation contract is discussed. Finally, the obtained conclusions are verified and expanded through a computing example.The studying results show that the private excessive investment behavior doesn't necessarily help to improve the expected social benefits for the project, but the government can always adjust the contract parameter to design the optimal compensation contract (maximizing the project's expected social benefit) which can adapt to the private different overconfidence behavior, and when the private excessive investment can't be observed, the government can select the optimal contract leading to the project's larger expected benefit according to the probability distribution for the private overconfidence.In summary, the results obtained in this paper not only contribute to the governmental compensation strategy, but also provide a better theoretical support for the implement of PPP project.
[1] 财政部,发展改革委,中国人民银行.关于在公共服务领域推广政府和社会资本合作模式的指导意见[M]. 北京: 人民出版社, 2015.
[2] Papajohn D, Cui Qinbin, Bayraktar M E. Public-private partnerships in U.S. transportation: Research overview and a path forward [J]. Journal of Management in Engineering, 2011, 27(3): 126-135.
[3] 周正祥, 张秀芳, 张平. 新常态下PPP模式应用存在的问题及对策[J]. 中国软科学, 2015, (9): 82-95.
[4] Peng Yichen, Zhou Jing, Wu Xiaoling,et al. Cost allocation in PPP projects: an analysis based on the theory of "contracts as reference " [J]. Discrete Dynamics in Nature and Society, 2014, 5(20): 1-6.
[5] Jun J. Appraisal of combined agreements in BOT project finance: Focused on minimum revenue guarantee and revenue cap agreements [J]. International Journal of Strategic Property Management, 2010, 14 (2):139-155.
[6] 赵立力, 卜祥智, 谭德庆. 基础设施BOT 项目中的两种政府保证研究[J]. 系统工程学报, 2009, 24 (2): 190-197.
[7] 高颖, 张水波, 冯卓. PPP项目运营期间需求量下降情形下的补偿机制研究[J]. 管理工程学报, 2015, 29(2): 93-102.
[8] Fearnley N, Bekken J T, Norhem B. Optimal performance-based subsidies in Norwegian intercity rail transport [J]. International Journal of Transport Management, 2004, 2(1): 29-38.
[9] Ho S P. Model for financial renegotiation in public-private partnership projects and its policy implications: Game theoretic view [J]. Journal of Construction Engineering and Management, 2006, 132(7):678-688.
[10] 王健, 安实, 赵泽斌. 基于财政补贴的拥挤定价下公交收费策略研究[J]. 管理工程学报, 2006, 20(2):84-89.
[11] 吴孝灵, 周晶, 彭以忱, 等. 基于公私博弈的PPP项目政府补偿机制研究[J]. 中国管理科学, 2013, 21(S1): 198-204.
[12] 吴孝灵, 周晶, 王冀宁, 等. 依赖特许收益的PPP项目补偿契约激励性与有效性[J]. 中国工程科学, 2014, 16(10): 77-83.
[13] Ulrike M, Geoffrey T,Yan JON.Internet appendix for overconfidence and early-life experiences: The effect of managerial traits on corporate financial policies [J]. The Journal of Finance, 2011, 66(5): 1687-1733.
[14] 张征争,黄登仕. 不同风险偏好的过度自信代理人薪酬合同设计[J]. 管理工程学报. 2009, 23(2): 104-110.
[15] Galasso A, Simcoe T S. CEO overconfidence and innovation [J]. Management Science, 2011, 57(8): 1469-1484.
[16] Gervais S, Heaton J B, Odean T. Overconfidence, compensation contracts, and capital budgeting [J]. The Journal of Finance, 2011, 66(5): 1735-1777.
[17] Cesarini D, Sandewall O, Johannesson M. Confidence interval estimation tasks and the economics of overconfidence [J]. Journal of Economic Behavior Organization, 2006, 61(3): 453-470.
[18] 郑敏, 郑苏晋. 在Klman-Bucy滤波学习过程下的投资者生存能力分析[J]. 中国管理科学, 2016, 24(1): 38-46.
[19] 扈文秀, 刘刚, 章伟果, 等. 基于因素嵌入的非理性资产价格泡沫生成及膨胀演化研究[J]. 中国管理科学, 2016, 24(5): 31-37.
[20] Shefrin H. Behavioral corporate finance [J]. Journal of Applied Corporate Finance, 2001, (14): 113-124.
[21] Jeremy K, Huang Zhijian. Arrogance can be a virtue: overconfidence, information acquisition, and market efficiency [J]. Journal of Financial Economics, 2007, 84(2): 529-560.
[22] Sandra L, Philipp C. Overconfidence can improve an agent's relative and absolute performance in contests [J]. Economics Letters, 2014, 110(3):193-196.
[23] dela Rosa L E. Overconfidence and moral hazard [J]. Games and Economic Behavior, 2011, 73(2): 429-451.
[24] 王健, 盛积良, 庄新田. 基金销售市场双边道德风险、理财经理过度自信与投资者利益保护[J].管理工程学报, 2016, 30(2): 133-141.
[25] 李娟, 郝忠原, 陈彩华. 过度自信委托代理人间的薪酬合同研究[J]. 系统工程理论与实践, 2014, 34(6): 1379-1387.
[26] 王健, 庄新田. 基于过度自信的资本市场委托代理关系[J]. 系统管理学报, 2008, 17(2): 189-195.
[27] 肖迪, 袁敬霞, 鲁其辉. 决策者过度自信视角下考虑质量控制的供应链库存策略[J]. 中国管理科学, 2014, 22(10): 59-65.
[28] 查博, 郭菊娥, 晏文隽. 风险投资三方委托代理关系—基于创业企业家过度自信与风投公司监督努力[J]. 系统管理学报, 2015, 24(2): 190-199.
[29] 陈克贵, 宋学锋, 王新宇, 等. 非对称过度自信水平下的激励机制研究[J]. 系统工程理论与实践, 2015, 35(7): 1887-1895.
[30] Bettignies J E, Ross T W. Public-private partnerships and the privatization of financing: An incomplete contracts approach [J]. International Journal of Industrial Organization, 2009, 27(3): 358-368.
[31] 汤薇, 陈森发, 仇向洋. 城市轨道交通周边土地估价[J]. 系统管理学报, 2007, 16(2): 185-188.
[32] 吴孝灵, 周晶, 王冀宁, 等. 基于CAPM的BOT项目"有限追索权"融资决策模型[J]. 管理工程学报, 2012, 26(2): 175-183.
[33] Hirshleifer D, Luo Guoying. On the survival of overconfident traders in a competitive securities market [J]. Journal of Financial Market, 2001, 4(1): 73-84.